Playing against a mixed strategy in class
This post if very late but I have been very busy with some really exciting things. I will describe some of the data gathered in class when we played against a random strategy played by a computer. I have recently helped organise a conference in Namibia teaching Python. It was a tremendous experience and I will write a post about that soon.
We played against a modified version of matching pennies which we have used quite a few times:
I wrote a sage interact that allows for a quick visualisation of a random sample from a mixed strategy. You can find the code for that at the blog post I wrote last year. You can also find a python script with all the data from this year here.
I handed out sheets of papers on which students would input their preferred strategies (‘H’ or ‘T’) whilst I sampled randomly from 3 different mixed strategies:
- \(\sigma_1 = (.2, .8)\)
- \(\sigma_1 = (.9, .1)\)
- \(\sigma_1 = (1/3, 2/3\)
Based on the class notation that implies that the computer was the row player and the students the column player. The sampled strategies were (we played 6 rounds for each mixed strategy):
- TTTTTH
- HHHHHH
- HTTTHH
Round 1
This mixed strategy (recall \(\sigma_1=(.2,.8)\)) implies that the computer will be mainly playing T (the second strategy equivalent to the second row), and so based on the bi-matrix it is in the students interest to play H. Here is a plot of the mixed strategy played by all the students:
The mixed strategy played was \(\sigma_2=(.71,.29)\). Note that in fact in this particular instance that actual best response is to play \(\sigma_2=(1,0)\). This will indeed maximise the expected value of:
Indeed: the above is an increasing linear function in \(x\) so the highest value is obtained when \(x=1\).
The mean score for this round by everyone was: 2.09. The theoretical mean score (when playing the best response for six consecutive games is): \(6(-.2\times 2+.8)=2.4\), so everybody was not too far off.
Here is a distribution of the scores:
We see that there were very few losers in this round, however no students obtained the best possible score: 7.
Round 2
Here the mixed strategy is \(\sigma_1=(.9,.1)\), implying that students should play T more often than H. Here is a plot of the mixed strategy played by all the students:
The mixed strategy played was \(\sigma_2=(.05,.95)\). Similarly to before this is close to the actual best response which is \((0,1)\) (due to the expected utility now being a decreasing linear function in \(x\).
The mean score for this round by everyone was: 10.69 The theoretical mean score (when playing the best response for six consecutive games is): \(6(.9\times 2-.1)=10.2\), which is less than the score obtained by the class (mainly because the random sampler did not actually pick T at any point).
Here is a distribution of the scores:
No one lost on this round and a fair few maxed out at 12.
Round 3
Here is where things get interesting. The mixed strategy played by the computer is here \(\sigma_1=(1/3,2/3)\), it is not now obvious which strategy is worth going for!
Here is the distribution played:
The mixed strategy is \(\sigma_2=(.61,.39)\) and the mean score was -.3. Here is what the distribution looked like:
It looks like we have a few more losers than winners but not by much. In fact I would suggest (because I know the theory covered in Chapter 5 of my class) that the students were in fact indifferent against this \(\sigma_1\). Indeed:
and
In fact, this particular \(\sigma_1\) ensures that the expected result for the students is not influenced by what they actually do:
What strategy could the students have played to ensure the same situation for the computer’s strategy? At the moment, the mixed strategy \(\sigma_2=(.61,.39)\) has expected utility for player 1 (the computer):
As this is an increasing function in \(x\) we see that the computer should in fact change \(\sigma_1\) to be \((1,0)\).
Thus if the original \(\sigma_1\) of this round is being played, so that the choice of \(\sigma_2\) does in fact not have an effect, students might as well play a strategy that ensures that the computer has no incentive to deviate (ie we are at a Nash equilibrium).
This can be calculated by solved the following linear equation:
which corresponds to:
which gives a strategy at which the computer has no incentive to deviated: \((1/2,1/2)\). Thus at \(\sigma_1=(1/3,2/3)\) and \(\sigma_2=(1/2,1/2)\) no players have an incentive to move: we are at a Nash equilibrium. This actually brings us back to another post I’ve written this term so please do go take a look at this post which involved students playing against each other and comparing to the Nash equilibrium.